Last year, the CER proposed a system of regulatory alignment focussed on goods, with the freedom to diverge in services, pointing out that this would be a sufficient quid pro quo for May’s decision to end the free movement of people, given the UK’s trade advantages in the services sector. For their part, the Institute for Government (IfG) and the Institute for Public Policy Research (IPPR), two British think-tanks, have found a solution in ‘managed divergence’: the UK and EU commit to regulatory alignment in some sectors, while allowing the UK to diverge from new rules in others in the future. The EU would be permitted to curtail market access in those sectors as a result. The British government is considering such a system.
There are attractions to such a half-way house for both sides. For the UK, it would soften the economic blow that a free trade agreement (FTA) would entail: even the most ambitious FTAs do not provide the regulatory alignment needed to allow goods and services to flow across borders without checks. Full participation in the single market through membership of the European Economic Area is too costly politically, since the UK would have to apply the EU’s rules but would have little say on adopting them. By reducing the number of sectors to which that nasty soft Brexit logic applies, the UK could limit the economic damage while regaining the perception of sovereignty over parts of its economy.
For the EU’s part, one of its main trade aims has always been to get non-EU countries to align with its rules and standards, rather than those of the US (much to the annoyance of Washington). The more the UK continues to abide by EU rules, the more readily its goods and services will be made available to EU consumers. A free trade agreement would lead to more checks and paperwork on UK imports at the EU’s border – especially in highly regulated sectors like agriculture, medical devices, pharmaceuticals, chemicals and cars, which would no longer be subject to the EU’s rules.
Yet, ‘managed divergence’ along the lines of the IfG and IPPR proposals is unlikely to gain traction among the 27.
For one, these proposals amount to cherry-picking, which the EU has made a red line. It is naïve to expect that the EU-27 will agree to a system where the UK converges when deemed to be in its interest, but diverges in those sectors in which it could gain competitive advantage with the rest of the world. The point of the single market is that all its members sign up to all rules, which cover the entire economy; if the UK wins opt-outs, then other countries will seek them too.
Second, the process of managed divergence would prove difficult to manage. It would be a political feat for the EU and UK to agree which rules are crucial for maintaining a level playing field, and which matter less. Certain rules matter for the operation of several different markets (chemical regulations have an impact on other markets for products that use those chemicals, as well as on the environment), and some are highly specific to a particular market. The EU would say that all markets are interlinked, and the UK would say that opt-outs in specific sectors would not provide competitive advantages in others. And, since the economic impact of regulations is very hard to identify objectively, any disputes could prove impossible to manage. If the UK chose to diverge from one part of the EU’s insurance regime, should the EU have the right to curtail market access in the sector as a whole?
The EU is unlikely to countenance any model which undermines the single market’s political integrity. In that regard neither the IPPR nor IfG proposals look likely to stick. However, a model that may limit the damage and prove politically palatable to the EU-27 exists: the UK remains in a comprehensive customs union with the EU and the single market, but only for goods. Under such an agreement, there would be no process of managed divergence in different sectors over time.
One could call this ‘the Jersey option’ (because the Crown Dependencies enjoy a similar relationship with the EU). The agreement would need to include the following features: